Skip to content
  • Categories
  • Recent
  • Tags
  • Popular
  • Users
  • Groups
Skins
  • Light
  • Cerulean
  • Cosmo
  • Flatly
  • Journal
  • Litera
  • Lumen
  • Lux
  • Materia
  • Minty
  • Morph
  • Pulse
  • Sandstone
  • Simplex
  • Sketchy
  • Spacelab
  • United
  • Yeti
  • Zephyr
  • Dark
  • Cyborg
  • Darkly
  • Quartz
  • Slate
  • Solar
  • Superhero
  • Vapor

  • Default (No Skin)
  • No Skin
Collapse

The New Coffee Room

  1. TNCR
  2. General Discussion
  3. Racial Preferences May Be Ending, but the Fight Will Continue

Racial Preferences May Be Ending, but the Fight Will Continue

Scheduled Pinned Locked Moved General Discussion
7 Posts 5 Posters 109 Views
  • Oldest to Newest
  • Newest to Oldest
  • Most Votes
Reply
  • Reply as topic
Log in to reply
This topic has been deleted. Only users with topic management privileges can see it.
  • HoraceH Offline
    HoraceH Offline
    Horace
    wrote on last edited by Horace
    #1

    A piece by John McWhorter. Apparently SCOTUS will rule any day now about racial preferences in college admissions.

    Progressives are going to be so embarrassed to learn that it was unconstitutional all along.

    Racial Preferences May Be Ending, but the Fight Will Continue
    by John McWhorter

    A recent argument about racial preferences gets me thinking about John Stuart Mill’s suggestion in On Liberty that a society regularly review arguments for and against controversial ideas, to ensure that all understand both sides. It is widely expected that the Supreme Court will soon outlaw racial preferences in university admissions.

    Many, including me and Richard Kahlenberg (see his book The Remedy), have argued that preferences should continue, but based on socioeconomics rather than race. Under this view, the simplistic equation of blackness with significant disadvantage, while understandable fifty years ago, is now obsolete.

    As my New York Times colleague David Brooks has recently flagged here, Kahlenberg has even calculated that socioeconomic preferences would actually bring in more black people than race-based ones, because of the very disproportion in poverty between blacks and whites that dismays us all. This would seem a kind of wisdom, but historian Richard Rothstein is against socioeconomic preferences, arguing that they would leave unaddressed the needs of middle-class black applicants. Rothstein is so sure of the moral unassailability of his position that he urges that schools and judges engage in civil disobedience if preferences are banned, modelling themselves on resistance to the Dred Scott decision.

    Really, though? Here, we need to review what constitutes the kind of obstacles that proponents of racial preferences cite to justify changing standards in college admissions.

    Yes, changing standards: We must use language as clearly as possible rather than settle for euphemism. Much discussion of racial preferences operates according to a polite pretense that brown students are chosen only from a pool in which all applicants have equivalent grades and test scores, with admissions committees then assembling a class seeking diversity. However, it has been resoundingly demonstrated in a large number of cases—such as this one—that racial preference policies involve, to various degrees, admitting brown students according to a lower bar of quantifiable performance than others. The only question is the degree to which standards are relaxed and whether the changes are justified.

    Returning, then, to Rothstein’s concern that socioeconomic preferences will unduly bypass middle-class black ones, a recent Times editorial by an Asian-American teen poses a relevant question: “How fair is a system that seems to give an affluent African American student an advantage over an underprivileged white or Asian American one, simply on the basis of skin color?” Rothstein thinks such a system is indeed fair, because almost all black people face race-based inequities, regardless of class. This perspective is hardly uncommon, if my twenty-five years’ experience in debates on preferences is any guide. But the argument is, frankly, a dud.

    Rothstein notes, for example, that middle-class black people have much less accumulated wealth than whites tend to. This is true, and the wealth gap between black and white people has actually increased of late. But the question is whether the wealth gap, in particular, requires that we change standards.

    In New York City, for example, immigrant families with little accumulated wealth regularly send their children to the most competitive high schools in the city. It is often argued that it is unfair to compare black students to immigrants, because they had a particularly pronounced incentive to come here and are therefore likely to push their kids harder than we have a right to expect native-born parents to. There is merit to the observation, but it leaves the wealth gap explanation wanting nevertheless. If South Asian immigrants’ kids can overcome the wealth gap, just why is a lack of inherited money and real estate suddenly a key factor for black American kids?

    Subscribed

    Share

    Then Rothstein argues that middle-class black kids have an additional problem: that they often live near poorer ones and thus acquire some of the reflexes that race-based inequities instill in their less advantaged neighbors, including a temptation to skirt the law. “Students from these middle-class Black neighborhoods who avoid such temptations are more likely than low-wealth Black students to be academically competitive, and they deserve affirmative action,” Rothstein notes.

    But let’s be clear about what Rothstein is actually arguing. We might reword the passage as follows: “Students from these middle-class Black neighborhoods who avoid such temptations are more likely than low-wealth Black students to be academically competitive, and they deserve to be evaluated according to lower standards on their grades and test scores.”

    The idea here would seem to be that, regardless of circumstances other than serious affluence, black students require a pass in order to compete with their non-black peers. Rothstein is hardly alone in such a perception, which in itself is humane and sincere. It demonstrates an understanding that racism and its legacies persist, and that in assessing a socioeconomic profile, the socio is as important as the economic. For example, black law professor Sheryll Cashin documents in her The Failures of Integration that, after a while, poorer black people have tended to relocate to or near the middle-class black communities that began flowering after the demise of redlining in the late 1960s, changing the general condition of the neighborhoods.

    But to take this as meaning that to be black and middle-class is to be so disadvantaged that one must adjust standards of scholastic evaluation is, I submit, a leap. It is even, albeit unintentionally, dismissive of the achievement of middle-class black families who have striven so hard, and successfully, to give their children comfortable lives.

    As a middle-class black kid in the 1970s and 1980s, I encountered racism now and then. Once a white kid called me “blackie.” Once a store owner quietly refused to hire me for a summer job because of my color (you could kind of smell it, and later I met an ex-employee of his who confirmed it). Also, in the neighborhoods I lived in—the very integrated Mt. Airy in Philadelphia and Warwick Hills in Lawnside, New Jersey, a then-newly built section of an all-black town— some black kids did drift into seedier activities in identifying with less fortunate peers (one neighbor kid of mine ended up actually doing time). And a middle-class black kid can be more subject to being stopped by police than middle-class white kids are, which is in line with what Rothstein and Cashin describe.

    However, the idea that these factors make it immoral to expect a middle-class black kid to pull off the grades and test scores that a white middle-class kid does is, frankly, condescending. In this, I speak not just for my nerdy self but the legions of middle-class black kids I grew up around, and the further legions there are today.

    I am not opposed to racial preferences in principle. I just think that they should be time-limited, and that at this point, the time limit is long past. In the 1960s, lowering standards for black kids overall, as justifiable redress of the past, was a fine idea in itself, especially as a greater proportion of black Americans were poor. The question is how long preferences should be maintained. Preferences inevitably entail that white and Asian kids of the same ability are somewhat “dispreferenced.” To insist that the ills of the past justify this dispreference for, say, one generation is one thing; to insist that the dispreference must be maintained until there are no racial inequities in society will never fully assuage families who are working just as hard as black ones are. Cases like Grutter v. Bollinger, Gratz v. Bollinger and Edward Blum’s cases against Harvard and North Carolina will never cease, and to dismiss those who initiate them as racists or ignorant of the nature of privilege is facile. The solution is not to never apply racial preferences—it’s good that we did a long time ago. But the idea must be to apply this compensation for the past—a reparation, as it were—in a time-limited fashion. That time came long ago.

    Contrast this with Rothstein arguing, almost six decades after racial preferences were first adopted, that we must maintain altered standards even for middle-class black kids. that this is so urgent that universities must flout the Supreme Court’s ban in the way that courts defied the Dred Scott decision. In our race discussions, I often can’t help detecting a quiet sense that black people just aren’t made for the school thing and that a moral society must grade all of us on a curve. I see this less as antiracism than condescension, a mild form of racial prejudice, which is neither a gift nor a compliment.

    Education is extremely important.

    1 Reply Last reply
    • JollyJ Offline
      JollyJ Offline
      Jolly
      wrote on last edited by
      #2

      Next thing you're going to tell me is that the time limit for reparations has passed.

      Boo-hoo-hoo...

      “Cry havoc and let slip the DOGE of war!”

      Those who cheered as J-6 American prisoners were locked in solitary for 18 months without trial, now suddenly fight tooth and nail for foreign terrorists’ "due process". — Buck Sexton

      1 Reply Last reply
      • HoraceH Offline
        HoraceH Offline
        Horace
        wrote on last edited by
        #3

        My favorite point in McWhorter's piece, is that with economic preferences rather than racial, blacks would be helped even more. I assume economic preferences would be much more widely accepted by the left and right.

        Education is extremely important.

        89th8 1 Reply Last reply
        • JonJ Offline
          JonJ Offline
          Jon
          wrote on last edited by
          #4

          I’m sure they would, but more importantly they wouldn’t be unconstitutional.

          HoraceH 1 Reply Last reply
          • JonJ Jon

            I’m sure they would, but more importantly they wouldn’t be unconstitutional.

            HoraceH Offline
            HoraceH Offline
            Horace
            wrote on last edited by
            #5

            @Jon said in Racial Preferences May Be Ending, but the Fight Will Continue:

            I’m sure they would, but more importantly they wouldn’t be unconstitutional.

            "More importantly" seems debatable, considering how long unconstitutional affirmative action survived.

            Education is extremely important.

            1 Reply Last reply
            • CopperC Offline
              CopperC Offline
              Copper
              wrote on last edited by
              #6

              And now all of us non-preferred races are ready to receive reparations.

              1 Reply Last reply
              • HoraceH Horace

                My favorite point in McWhorter's piece, is that with economic preferences rather than racial, blacks would be helped even more. I assume economic preferences would be much more widely accepted by the left and right.

                89th8 Offline
                89th8 Offline
                89th
                wrote on last edited by
                #7

                @Horace said in Racial Preferences May Be Ending, but the Fight Will Continue:

                My favorite point in McWhorter's piece, is that with economic preferences rather than racial, blacks would be helped even more. I assume economic preferences would be much more widely accepted by the left and right.

                It's almost painful how "common sense" that is instead of how much melanin your skin has. We will look back at the previous policy with judging eyes for how stupid it was.

                1 Reply Last reply
                Reply
                • Reply as topic
                Log in to reply
                • Oldest to Newest
                • Newest to Oldest
                • Most Votes


                • Login

                • Don't have an account? Register

                • Login or register to search.
                • First post
                  Last post
                0
                • Categories
                • Recent
                • Tags
                • Popular
                • Users
                • Groups